Marx in the Anthropocene: Towards the Idea of Degrowth Communism
By Kohei Saito
Cambridge University Press
Due for release in early 2023
Kohei Saito is an associate professor at Tokyo University and an erudite Marxist scholar. Not a candidate for a best-seller in the non-fiction book world, you might think. But you would be wrong in this case. Saito鈥檚 new book (currently in Japanese), which analyses the relationship between capitalism and the planet, has been a smash hit in Japan, with over half a million sales already.
In the English version out shortly, the book is entitled, Marx in the Anthropocene: Towards the Idea of Degrowth Communism.
The book鈥檚 message is stark and clear. Capitalism鈥檚 rapacious drive for profit is destroying the planet and only 鈥渄egrowth鈥 can repair the damage by slowing down social production and sharing wealth.聽 Humans need to find a 鈥渘ew way of living鈥, and that means replacing capitalism.
Saito is deeply sceptical of some widely accepted strategies for tackling the climate emergency. 鈥淚n my book, I start a sentence by describing sustainable development goals [SDGs] as the new opium of the masses,鈥 he said in reference to Marx鈥檚 view of religion. 鈥淏uying eco bags and bottles without changing anything about the economic system 鈥 SDGs mask the systemic problem and reduce everything to the responsibility of the individual, while obscuring the responsibility of corporations and politicians.
鈥淲e face a very difficult situation: the pandemic, poverty, climate change, the war in Ukraine, inflation 鈥 it is impossible to imagine a future in which we can grow the economy and at the same time live in a sustainable manner without fundamentally changing anything about our way of life.
鈥淚f economic policies have been failing for 30 years, then why don鈥檛 we invent a new way of life? The desire for that is suddenly there.鈥
Saito reckons it is necessary to end mass production and the mass consumption of wasteful goods such as fast fashion. In his earlier, more academic text in English, called Capital in the Anthropocene, Saito also advocates decarbonisation through shorter working hours and prioritising essential 鈥渓abour-intensive鈥 work such as caregiving. In effect, Saito promotes what could be called 鈥榙e-growth Communism鈥.
Saito鈥檚 uncompromising message has seemingly captured the imagination of Japan鈥檚 youth. 鈥淪aito is telling a story that is easy to understand,鈥 says Jun Shiota, a 31-year-old researcher who bought Capital in the Anthropocene soon after it was published. 鈥淗e doesn鈥檛 say there are good and bad things about capitalism, or that it is possible to reform it 鈥 he just says we have to get rid of the entire system.鈥
In his academic work, Saito has followed John Bellamy Foster and Paul Burkett, in showing that it is wrong to claim, as some Greens do, that Marx and Engels ignored the impact of capitalism on the planet and the environment.聽 In particular, Saito won the Isaac Deutscher prize in 2018 for his learned analysis of Marx鈥檚 notebooks on agriculture and exhaustion of the soil revealing Marx鈥檚 deep interest in ecology.
In this earlier work, Saito points out that his approach 鈥渋s a clear continuation of the 鈥渕etabolic rift鈥 theory advocated by Foster and Burkett鈥. Saito argues that it is quite apparent today that mass production and consumption under capitalism has a tremendous influence on the global landscape and causes ecological crises. So Marxist theory needs to respond to the situation with a clear practical demand that envisages a sustainable society beyond capitalism. Capitalism and material conditions for sustainable production are incompatible. This is the basic insight of ecosocialism. The antagonism between red and green needs to be dissolved.
In his earlier book on Marx鈥檚 notes on agriculture under capitalism, Saito reckons that Marx attempted to analyse how the logic of capital diverges from the eternal natural cycle and ultimately causes various disharmonies in the metabolic interaction between humans and nature. Marx analysed this point with reference to Justus von Liebig鈥檚 critique of modern 鈥渞obbery鈥 agriculture 鈥 Raubbau 鈥 which takes as much nutrition as possible from the soil without returning any. This is driven by profit maximisation, which is simply incompatible with the material conditions of the soil for sustainable production. Thus, there emerges a grave gap between the logic of capital鈥檚 valorisation and that of nature鈥檚 metabolism, ie 鈥榤etabolic rifts鈥 in human interaction with the environment.
In the key passage on the concept of the metabolic rift, Marx wrote that the capitalist mode of production 鈥減roduces conditions that provoke an irreparable rift in the interdependent process between social metabolism and natural metabolism prescribed by the natural laws of the soil. The result of this is a squandering of the vitality of the soil, and trade carries this devastation far beyond the bounds of a single country (Liebig)鈥.聽With an expansion of capitalist accumulation, the metabolic rift becomes a global issue. So for Saito, ecosocialism argues that the ecological crisis and metabolic rift is the central contradiction of capitalism.
According to Saito, in The German Ideology, written in 1845, there was a turning point in Marx鈥檚 travel towards an 鈥渆cological dimension鈥 in his critique of capitalism. Saito reckons this is when he began to use the term 鈥渕etabolism鈥 and refined his understanding of the concept as the general metabolic tendency of capital. Saito argues that Marx progressively realised that capital鈥檚 continuous expansion exploits not just labour, but also nature in the search for profit, leading to the destruction of the soil, deforestation and other such forms of the degradation of natural resources. Capital wants more and more value and, in particular, surplus value. That becomes the purpose of production and the metabolic harmony that existed between humans and nature before capitalism is broken. There is now a metabolic rift caused by capitalism.
Now there is a debate about whether using the term 鈥渕etabolic rift鈥 is useful because it suggests, at least to me, that at some time in the past before capitalism there was some metabolic balance or harmony between humans, on the one hand, and 鈥渘ature鈥, on the other. Any emphasis on rifts or ruptures has the risk of assuming that nature is in harmony or in balance until capitalism disturbs it. But nature is never in balance, even without humans. It is always changing, evolving, with 鈥減unctuated equilibriums鈥 to use the term of Marxist paleaontologist Stephen Jay Gould 鈥 such as the Cambrian explosion, with many species evolving as others go extinct. The rule of the dinosaurs and their eventual extinction had nothing to do with humans (despite what the movies may depict). And humans have never been in a position to dictate conditions on the planet or with other species without repercussions. Nature lays down the environment for humans and humans act on nature. To quote Marx: "Men make their own history, but they do not make it just as they please; they do not make it under circumstances chosen by themselves, but under circumstances directly encountered and inherited from the past."
It鈥檚 true that Marx refers to the robbing of the soil by capitalist production. In Capital, Volume I, Chapter 15 on machinery Marx says: 鈥淢oreover, all progress in capitalist agriculture is a progress in the art, not only of robbing the worker, but of robbing the soil; all progress in increasing the fertility of the soil for a given time is a progress towards ruining the more long-lasting sources of that fertility. The more a country proceeds from large-scale industry as the background of its development 鈥 the more rapid is this process of destruction. Capitalist production, therefore, only develops the techniques and the degree of combination of the social process of production by simultaneously undermining the original sources of all wealth 鈥 the soil and the worker.鈥
Saito argues that 鈥淢arx鈥檚 critique of political economy, if completed, would have put a much stronger emphasis on the disturbance of the 鈥渕etabolic interaction鈥 between humanity and nature as the fundamental contradiction of capitalism.鈥澛燭hat may be Saito鈥檚 view, but was it Marx鈥檚? Is the metabolic rift the 鈥渇undamental contradiction of capitalism鈥? In my view, Saito does not offer a justification for this claim.
For Marx, capitalism was a system of 鈥渂rutal exploitation鈥 of labour power in production for profit, not one of robbery or dispossession. For Marx, agriculture under capitalism is a sector that exploits labour in the same way as industry. Marx rejected the Ricardian theory that the profitability of capital tended to fall because of diminishing returns in agriculture. Marx鈥檚 law of tendency of the rate of profit to fall depended on a rising 鈥渙rganic鈥 composition of capital (the word 鈥渙rganic鈥 perhaps taken from Liebig, as Saito suggests), where the material value of machinery and natural materials rises in cost relative to the exploitation of labour power. But contrary to Saito鈥檚 conclusion, Marx rejected Liebig鈥檚 soil exhaustion theory of the limits of capitalism and rejected the implied Malthusianism that population would outrun the availability of food and the necessities for human life.
Saito鈥檚 book is subtitled: 鈥楾owards the idea of de-growth communism鈥. 聽De-growth has become increasingly popular among many environmentalists and leftists. Jason Hickel, a prominent proponent of de-growth, defines it like this: "The objective of degrowth is to scale down the material and energy throughput of the global economy, focusing on high-income nations with high levels of per-capita consumption."
There is a big debate here 鈥 as expressed in by ex-World Bank chief economist and expert on global inequality, Branco Milanovic. Milanovic argues that any proposal to redistribute income and wealth to the global South by stopping or even reducing accumulation and GDP growth in the rich countries is economically irrational and politically infeasible. De-growth proponents like the de-growth argument because he has a 鈥渂lind faith鈥 in economic growth. I leave the readers here to consider the arguments.聽
Suffice it to say now that, under capitalism, accumulation happens for accumulation鈥檚 sake, to invest more and thus to make more profits without a plan and purely in the interests of private profit. When workers are in control of the surplus, will we not develop and grow the productive forces to make life better and easier for ourselves and more sustainable for the earth and its inhabitants? Wouldn鈥檛 we especially expand 鈥済reen鈥 productive forces to build say, more (and better) schools, public transportation, etc? Shouldn鈥檛 socialists strive to repair the underdevelopment created by imperialism by assisting in the development of productive forces in the formerly colonised world?
鈥淵et for all its stinginess, capitalist production is thoroughly wasteful with human material, just as its way of distributing its products through trade, and its manner of competition, make it very wasteful of material resources, so that it loses for society what it gains for the individual capitalist.鈥 The wasteful and environmentally unsustainable consumption patterns of the working class are not produced by 鈥減ersonal鈥 choice but are system-induced.
But the proponents of de-growth seem to argue that there are absolute 鈥減lanetary limits鈥 and a fixed 鈥渃arrying capacity鈥 that cannot be surpassed by humans if we want to avoid ecological collapse. Here there鈥檚 no distinction between socially produced limits and natural limits. But degrading nature, exterminating species and threatening to destroy the atmosphere of the planet are the result of the contradictions to be found in the capitalist mode of production itself, not in some existential threat from outside the system. Increased rates of pollution and environmental degradation occur because capitalists pursue profits at the expense of the environment, not because of the technologies themselves. Socialists should distinguish between the instruments of production and their use under capitalism.
In a socialist de-growth scenario, the goal would be to scale down ecologically destructive and socially less necessary production (what some might call the exchange value part of the economy), while protecting and indeed even enhancing parts of the economy that are organised around human well-being and ecological regeneration (the use value part of the economy).
Saito is right that ending the dialectical contradiction between humans and nature and bringing about some level of harmony and ecological balance would only be possible with the abolition of the capitalist mode of production. As Engels said: 鈥淭o carry out this control requires something more than mere knowledge.鈥 Science is not enough. 鈥淚t requires a complete revolution in our hitherto existing mode of production, and with it of our whole contemporary social order.鈥
[Michael Roberts is the author of The Great Recession 鈥 a Marxist view (2009); The Long Depression (2016); Marx 200: a review of Marx鈥檚 economics (2018): and jointly with Guglielmo Carchedi as editors of World in Crisis (2018). This article originally appeared on and is reprinted with permission.]