Bolivarian Socialism and the anti-blockade law in Venezuela

November 6, 2020
Issue 
Venezuelan President Nicolas Maduro.

Atilio Boron, an Argentine political scientist and Professor at the University of Buenos Aires, : 鈥淩evolutions aren鈥檛 carried out neatly and with the inexorable logic of trigonometric theorems. Revolution is like an immense cauldron in which historical processes are forged, with all their human limitations and social contradictions.鈥

This statement has assumed renewed significance as leftists debate the contentious anti-blockade law by the Venezuelan National Constituent Assembly (ANC) on October 8.

The law opens the door for privatisation in strategic economic sectors and grants the government the option to act with confidentiality and secrecy while the United States blockade and sanctions are in effect.

However, it was that the state-run oil company Petroleum of Venezuela (PDVSA) will not be privatised and full sovereignty over hydrocarbons and other natural resources will not be given up.

Furthermore, while the law favours private initiatives, Chavista organiser Oliver Rivas 鈥渋t is also the case that it allows for the participation of the state and organised popular power鈥.

The Bolivarian Revolution

Behind the intense discussion of the anti-blockade law, one can observe the problems posed by advancing socialism through the electoral system and within the contradictory and unfavourable context of representative democracy and property regimes that support capitalism.

Venezuela鈥檚 Bolivarian Revolution 鈥 initiated in 1998 by the late socialist president Hugo Chavez - attempted to facilitate transformational social changes by operating inside the bourgeoisie state apparatuses and gradually subverting it.

Venezuela鈥檚 process of change (el proceso) turned out to be extremely difficult. As Juan Carlos Monedero , 鈥淓ven when popular parties with redistributive agendas have won electoral majorities and gained, in principle, access to the governmental levers of power, they face a host of obstacles in implementing their campaign promises.

鈥淭hey do not enter into full possession of the state, as if it were a new home: the rooms may be booby-trapped, the stairs barricaded; there may be snipers in the kitchen 鈥 shooters who are unseen because they are taken for granted, and all the more effective because unseen.鈥

The debate around the anti-blockade law is a contemporary manifestation of the sustained efforts to negotiate through the obstacles set up by the pre-existing bourgeois state. When Chavez came to power, a new economic model 鈥 ideologically oiled with the aspirations of an ultimate transition to socialism 鈥 was adopted.

This growth model consisted of a combination of commercial surpluses (guaranteed by oil exports) and subsequent expansion of domestic demand by means of cheaper imports (which acted as indirect subsidies to domestic consumption), public investments, and social expenditures. All this was interspersed with increasing expropriations, nationalisations and the augmentation of worker presence on state company boards.

In addition to oil revenues, Chavez also tried to diversify the economy. He billions of dollars from oil revenues in agriculture, massive educational programs and in new industrial production facilities, 鈥渞anging from cell-phones to automobiles to bicycles to petrochemical products鈥.

Yet, the final result of these diversification efforts turned out to be limited due to two reasons.

Firstly, the presence of an overvalued currency, which makes imports significantly cheaper than domestically produced goods, acted as an impediment in the development of diversified productive forces.

Overvaluation took place in 2003 when the government established currency controls in the midst of increasing political tension and under the pressure of massive capital flight. Under the new rules, companies that wanted to import goods and services had to buy dollars from the national commission for the administration of foreign exchange (CADIVI).

While the measure helped to fight capital outflow, the exchange rate between the bolivar and the dollar the former, thus encouraging capitalists to change their bolivars for dollars, which are sold cheaply by the state, and import products from elsewhere, rather than produce them in the country. In this way, the policy of an overvalued bolivar discouraged diversification.

Secondly, the combined effects of a US-backed imperialist offensive and an internal counter-revolution carried out by a murderous, coup-mongering opposition greatly damaged Venezuela鈥檚 overall progress in the diversification of production.

Reactionary groups manufactured a series of macro-economically destabilising offensives, aimed at the violent destruction of the Chavista administration. Anti-Chavista attacks have taken the form of induced shortages, speculation, financial shocks, sanctions on production, violent uprisings (guarimbas), paramilitary activity, assassinations of Chavista leaders and organised disinformation campaigns.

Chavez鈥檚 neo-developmental and state-driven plan was coupled with a communal-socialist architecture tasked with the facilitation of self-governance through participatory forums.

The rationale behind this idea was clearly by Chavez: 鈥淲e have to head towards the creation of a communal state. And the old bourgeois state, which is still alive and kicking 鈥 this we have to progressively dismantle, at the same time as we build up the communal state, the socialist state, the Bolivarian state, a state that is capable of carrying through a revolution.鈥

Communal councils (groupings of 200-400 families involved in self-governance projects in densely populated urban areas, and 50-100 families in rural areas) were established in 2006, followed by the creation of communes (self-governing units which aggregated smaller existing units) in 2010.

There are more than 45,000 communal councils. Many have been joined together into larger communes, of which there are more than 1500. The communal councils are brought together with 鈥渟ocial property enterprises鈥 which are socialised units of production.

By unevenly reversing neoliberalism through (a) increased public spending, (b) the construction of a participatory governance structure, and (c) nationalisation, appropriation and development of industries and companies, socialism was reintroduced into the political lexicon.

The discursive and economic re-articulation of socialism antagonised and alienated the elites who had thought of the state as their instrument of self-enrichment. Therefore, the ties between the Chavistas and the private sector remained tenuous.

In order to redominate the state, the capitalists ruthlessly an 鈥渆conomic war鈥, of induced inflation, orchestrated shortages, a relative decrease of imports with respect to the foreign exchange delivered to the private sector, hoarding by oligopolistic companies that dominate the markets of specific goods and smuggling (mainly to Colombia).

To achieve a minimal level of politico-economic stability, the Chavista administration has had to establish tactical alliances with the bourgeoisie. These alliances have a contradictory character.

On the one hand, they slow down the tempo of revolution by giving concessions to the bourgeoisie. On the other hand, they prepare a semi-stable environment with reduced volatility, providing the government with an elbow room for future maneuvers.

This conflictual framework of social transformation is summed up by the Marxist theorist Roland Boer in the following : 鈥淲hat is possible in the existing conditions determines the conduct on the path, while the finally possible ensures that one does not mistake partial achievements for the goal itself, even concealing that goal.鈥

The contradictory nature of the anti-blockade law

The concrete contextualisation of the anti-blockade law in the richly-textured history of the Bolivarian Revolution makes it clear that it is an embodiment of the contradictory tendencies faced by a process of change. Due to the blockade, sanctions and an economic war, Venezuela鈥檚 national wealth has rapidly depleted. To temporarily end the brutal counter-revolution being carried out by the bourgeoisie, the anti-blockade law will use capitalist methods to re-accumulate wealth and form tactical alliances with the bourgeoisie.

It is important to remember that the economic strategy being implemented by the new law is internally contradictory and is a result of an economic impasse. The Marxist economist Ernest Mandel once : 鈥淕rowing productive forces with growing commodity-money relationships can in fact move a society farther from the socialist goal instead of bringing it closer. However, abolition of the commodity-money relationships without sufficient growth of the productive forces decays into rationalisation of scarcity, which in turn moves socialism farther off, both objectively and subjectively.鈥

Therefore, the anti-blockade law is an extremely delicate legal tool aimed at carefully re-configuring the correlation of class forces. In the current conjuncture, Chavistas need to properly utilise the law so that it ultimately makes it possible to advance on the long road to socialism.

[Yanis Iqbal is a student and freelance writer based in Aligarh, India and can be contacted at yanisiqbal@gmail.com.]

You need 麻豆传媒, and we need you!

麻豆传媒 is funded by contributions from readers and supporters. Help us reach our funding target.

Make a One-off Donation or choose from one of our Monthly Donation options.

Become a supporter to get the digital edition for $5 per month or the print edition for $10 per month. One-time payment options are available.

You can also call 1800 634 206 to make a donation or to become a supporter. Thank you.